In 1989 Hernando de Soto published the landmark book . de Soto argued that the informal sector holds the key to the aspirations of the world’s poor for robust, inclusive economic growth. Governments could unleash the creativity of small-scale entrepreneurs by removing rigid bureaucratic regulations and providing secure titles to property.
Yet nearly 30 years later, many developing countries retain large informal sectors dominated by firms with low productivity. In many countries of South Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa, for example, over 90 percent of the labor force is employed informally.
“It’s important to understand the causes of informality and its consequences for the development process so we can figure out when it makes sense to encourage formalization,” said Research Director Asli Demirguc-Kunt, who recently hosted a Policy Research Talk on the topic.
Norman Loayza, a Lead Economist at the World Bank who has studied informality for two decades, outlined two schools of thought that have dominated discussions of informality. One camp has claimed that informality is a consequence of a lack of development, and a failure to put in place sufficient protections for workers. Another camp has argued that it’s the result of bad governance—whether through excessive regulation, poor government services, or a combination of the two.
Seeking higher ground, Loayza proposed a synthesis between these two schools of thought. This synthesis focuses on the trade-offs leading to informality that social and economic agents face. Policy makers, for instance, face a trade-off between taxation for the provision of public services and the possibility of tax evasion. Likewise, owners of firms face a trade-off between high relative costs of labor in the formal sector and high relative costs of capital in the informal sector.